Buscar en
Journal of Innovation & Knowledge
Toda la web
Inicio Journal of Innovation & Knowledge R & D competition and patent values
Journal Information
Vol. 8. Issue 1.
(January - March 2023)
Share
Share
Download PDF
More article options
Visits
662
Vol. 8. Issue 1.
(January - March 2023)
Open Access
R & D competition and patent values
Visits
662
Pu-yan NIE, Hong-xing WEN
Corresponding author
pynie2013@163.com

Corresponding author.
, Chan WANG
School of Economics, Institute of Guangdong High-quality Development, National Economics Research Center, Guangdong University of Finance &Economics (GDUFE), Guangzhou, 510320, China
This item has received

Under a Creative Commons license
Article information
Abstract
Full Text
Bibliography
Download PDF
Statistics
Abstract

Research and development (R & D) competition is standard, and it heavily affects patent values. This study captures R&D competition's effects on patent values using game-theory approaches. Cost-reduction patent values increase with technology level and decrease with the competition. Technology spillover's impact on innovation depends on R & D's properties. This study elucidates cooperative R & D and the allocation mechanism, and also develops the theory of cooperative innovation.

Keywords:
Patent values
R & D competition
Patent industrialization
Full Text
Introduction

Realizing patent or intellectual property (IP) is extremely important to promote the economy worldwide. To attain certain targets, firms have to compete to launch research and development (R & D) activities. For example, several firms compete to develop a coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19) vaccine to cope with the spread of COVID-19 (Graham, 2020; Heaton, 2020; Le et, al., 2020). Since April 8, 2021, 155 COVID-19 vaccines have been developed worldwide—including mRNA-1273 of Moderna,Ad5-nCoVof CanSino Biologicals,INO-4800 of Inovio, andLV-SMENP-DC and pathogen-specific aAPC of Shenzhen Geno-Immune Medical Institute (Le et al., 2020). To date, only nine COVID-19 vaccines are permitted for use. Efficient COVID-19 vaccines are now in production owing to R&D competition. (Minin et al., 2021).

According to the earlier example, the R&D competition stimulated the progress of COVID-19 vaccines. Moreover, according to data obtained from the China National Intellectual Property Administration (cnipa.gov.cn), launched on July 13, 2022, the rewards of patents are 4.5 times of investments in 2021 and 4.4 times in 2020.Thus, capturing R&D competition's effects is important. Based on the above background, this study addresses R&D competition affecting patent prices using game theory approaches. Moreover, patents are closely related to technological levels. The technology level generally measures the degree of technological expertise and advances. Therefore, production efficiency and cost are two important symbols of technology levels. This study refers to the technology level with the costs incurred on production. Higher technology-level patents yield lower marginal production costs.

This study's contributions lie in both its theories and applications. This study establishes a theory on R & D competition-related patent prices. Low-level patents harm consumer surplus, presenting both the effects of technology spillover on R&D and conditions for technology spillover to improve (or reduce) R & D. Further, it elucidates cooperative R & D mechanisms and allocation benefits.

Policy implications have been proposed for applications. The government should identify technology levels corresponding to patents and reject patents with low technology levels. Further, technology spillover impacts R&D, and IP protection should consider the situation to promote R & D. Moreover, cooperative R & D should be encouraged.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the literature on patent values and stresses the importance of the topic. Section 3 establishes a model of patent values for the two research firms. Subsequently, Section 4 analyzes and discusses the model. Finally, Section 5 concludes the paper.

Literature review

Since the pioneering work of Arrow (1962), R&D has been conducted by scholars and society worldwide. Acemoglu et al. (2018) argued that innovation is the basis of economic growth, whereas Aghion and Jaravel (2015) discussed that technological innovation and spillover stimulatesocietal progress. Kogan et al. (2017) found that technological innovation improves resource allocation and has yielded economic growth in recent years. Nie and Yang (2020) argued that cost-reduction innovation promotes consumer surplus. The importance of innovation indicatesthat patents are needed to encourage innovation.

Patent values are important because they are crucial in patent industrialization. For example, Cockburn et al. (2016) found that patents globally affect new drug diffusion. Quintino et al. (2021) found that intellectual property assets significantly affect innovation efficiency. Taehyuk and Ilwon (2021) highlighted that patents yield first-mover advantages for firms in the entire market. Ribeiro and Shapira (2020) identified differences in patents between public and private firms and demonstrated that private firms benefit more from patents. Based on this, Fan et al. (2018) proposed optimal patents under incomplete information in theory.

Research on patent values has highlighted various factors affecting patent prices. For instance, Nie, Chen and Wang (2021) discussed patent prices under oligopoly competition and proved that weaker firms exhibit a stronger intention to buy patents to pursue advantageous firms. Chen et al. (2022) argued that firms earn from the bundling sale pattern of patents if the two patents are closely related under Cournot and Stackelberg competition. Nie, Wang and Wen (2023) argued that technology standards promote patent values. Sen and Stamatopoulos (2019) proved that price-decreasing taxes decrease patent values. Nie, Wang and Wen (2022) argued that technology spillovers reduce patent prices. Interestingly, based on the human genome, Williams (2013) addressed how research tools on patents harm innovation and opposed intellectual property protection on research tools. Recently, under incomplete information, Song and Zhao (2021) found that strategic disclosure of intellectual property may stimulate innovation and suggested the exact IP protection to promote innovation. Donduran and Ünveren (2021) discussed cooperative innovation or cooperative patents and found that competitive R&D yields overinvestment.

We address some policy implications based on the corresponding theory and prior empirical research. Lim (1998) argued that patent policy plays an important role in influencing R&D. Zeng et al. (2014) proposed price regulation to promote innovation. Kwon (2021) proposed a patent policy to identify weak patents to strengthen patent industrialization and maintain high-level innovation.

Although competition affecting patent values has been discussed previously, no studies have considered patent values under R&D competition, which signifies that a potent entrant of a patent invariably exists, and this potent entrant impacts the research firm to price patents. This study aims to fill this research gap by capturing the patent values under R & D competition. Moreover, the duopoly competition model is introduced into R & D competition. In this model, the technology level is related to the marginal costs incurred on production. Industrial organizations have been introduced in the R & D field. This enriches the R & D model and analysis framework.

Model establishment

The model is established with a patent and two research firms in this industry. Che, Iossa and Rey (2021) assumed that research firms exist in the industry. We assume Nproduction firms in this industry with marginal costs ci>0,i=1,2,⋯,N. Without loss of generality, we assume that 0

Producers. Without this patent, firms’ profits are stated as follows:

This patent is priced as pp>0, and the costs incurred by this patent arecp>0. Moreover, based on the exclusion rules, we further assume that this patent is sold to a unique production firm. We assume that firm K buys this patent and that the corresponding profit function is

Moreover, the market size is sufficiently large, and this study invariably assumes that A>>maxj=1,2,⋯,N{cj}. The market size is exceedingly larger than the marginal costs incurred on production, which guarantees all firms’ production.

Research firms. Two research firms in this industry that compete in R&D are introduced and denoted as {A,B}. The two research firms launched a patent competition, and one achieved a patent. We assume that the two research firms spend I=(IA,IB) in R&D. The probability of obtaining a patent along with the production costs c¯ is

In Eq. (5), γ∈[0,1] indicates the degree of technology spillover. hj(•),j∈{A,B} satisfies hj(0)=0,j∈{A,B} and is concave; that is, dhj(x)dx≥0 and d2hj(x)dx2<0.The assumption regarding this patent, along with the production costs c¯, is to simplify the model, and it is easy to extend the general situation.

The timing of game theory is as follows: In the first stage, two research firms compete in R & D, and a research firm owns a patent and prices to production firms. In the second stage, a production firm buys this patent, and no firms buy it. In the final stage, firms compete in terms of quantity.

Discussion

Backward induction is adopted to discuss the above model. The third stage is addressed, the second stage is discussed, and finally, the first stage is analyzed.

The third stage

The third stage is discussed in two cases. One is that no firm buys this patent, and the other is that firm K buys this patent.

Case 1. no firm buys this patent

Without a patent, this situation constitutes classical Cournot competition. Equilibrium is calculated using (2). The profit functions are all concave, and the equilibrium is determined by the first-order optimal conditions as follows:

The equilibrium is

The assumption of A>>maxj=1,2,⋯,N{cj} implies that each output is positive. Moreover, the corresponding price and profits are represented

Case 2. firm K buys this patent

In this case, equilibrium is achieved using Eq. (3). Like case 1, the equilibrium is outlined as follows:

The corresponding price and profits are

Based on the above equilibrium, we obtain the following conclusion:

Proposition 1 Patent realization promotes total output or consumer surplus under c¯≤cK. Otherwise, the consumer surplus undergoes a loss owing to patent industrialization.

Proof. See Appendix.

Remarks: Condition c¯>cKindicates that the technology level with patent realization is higher than in the initial stage. In this situation, patent industrialization promotes output while reducing the price of final goods. Thus, the consumer surplus is correspondingly improved. Otherwise, the technology is extremely low, and this industry suffers a loss because of the introduction of patents. The policy implies encouraging high-value patents or technology threshold values while preventing low-technology patents. A restriction on the technology level is suggested for the government to improve consumer surplus. Patent applications should focus on technology levels.

Second stage

At this stage, firm Kdetermines whether to buy this patent. This firm buys the patent if and only if the following principles apply for a profit-incentive firm:

The above inequality implies that the firm benefits from this patent. We re-write Eq. (13) as follows:

We denote V*=N(cK−c¯)N+1(qK2,*+qK1,*)by the threshold value for a firm to buy this patent. For the above threshold value, the following result holds:

Proposition 2 Underc¯≤cK, the patent price's threshold value increases with the technology level and decreases with the competition.

Proof. See Appendix.

Remarks: This proposition illustrates the relationship between the technology level and threshold values. Higher technology levels imply lower expected costs, and the threshold values are correspondingly promoted.

The relationship between competition and innovation has long been debated. Arrow (1962) proposed that competition promotes innovation. Gilbert and Newbery (1982) opposed Arrow's assumptions and demonstrated that monopolists are more incentivized to launch innovation. The above conclusion also supports the important idea of Gilbert and Newbery (1982) in theory from another angle.

The first stage

This patent is sold if and only if the following conditions are fulfilled:

From Eq. (14), this research firm benefits from this R&D; otherwise,pp>V*suggests that the production firm has no intention to buy this patent because the price is extremely high. cp>ppindicates that the research firm incurs high costs, and the trade between the research firm and production firm fails. When Eq. (15) is not satisfied, the government may subsidize the research firm or production firm to advance R&D and patent industrialization (Nie et al., 2020; Che, Iossa & Rey, 2021). For the research firm, the expected earnings are prjpp. The participation condition is as follows:

Otherwise, the firm quits R&D to avoid undertaking losses. Eq. (16) can be restated as follows:
In (17), −j∈{A,B},−j≠j. Considering the patent values, we obtain the following conclusion:

Proposition 3 High technology spillover levels reduce innovative investment underexp(−hj(Ij+γI−j))pp∂hj∂Ij>1. Otherwise, technology spillovers promote innovative investments.

Proof. See Appendix.

Remarks: Under high technology spillover and exp(−hj(Ij+γI−j))pp∂hj∂Ij>1, this R&D exhibits a high probability of success, and firms reduce RR & D because all firms benefit from the opponents’ R & D. Thus, high technology spillover yields a free-rider phenomenon. The policy implication is the launch of copyright protection to reduce technology spillovers for highly potential R & D. Thus, firms tend to invest in R&D.

Fromexp(−hj(Ij+γI−j))pp∂hj∂Ij<1, R & D faces low patent prices and a low probability of success, and technology spillover encourages R&D investment. The corresponding policy implication is encouraging technology spillover because technology spillover stimulates innovation.

Otherwise under exp(−hj(Ij+γI−j))pp∂hj∂Ij≥1, technology spillover deters innovation, and the policy implication is the launch of strict patent protection to prevent technology spillover. Thus, R & D is maintained.

In summary, the policy implication is that optimal copyright protection depends on innovation properties. To launch optimal policies, patent properties and the market should be highlighted carefully.

We further discuss a symmetric situation wherein hA=hBoccurs. Moreover, cooperative R & D has also been addressed (Wang &, Nie,2021). Firms cooperatively innovate if and only if the following conditions hold.

We assume that two research firms launch R & D as (IA*,3,IB*,3). This cooperative R&D's earnings are in pp−IA*,3−IB*,3. These extra earnings’ allocation is:

In summary, because of technology spillover, firms underinvest in R&D. A cooperative R&D mechanism is proposed, and allocation is suggested based on the investment.

Concluding remarks

This study focuses on R&D's effects on patent value. Conversely, cost-reduction patent values increase with the technology level and decrease with the competition. By contrast, technology spillover may stimulate or deter innovation depending on R&D's properties. Further, cooperative R & D and the allocation mechanism are proposed.

Based on these results, we suggest some policy implications. First, the government should identify patents with a high technology level because patents with low technology negatively impact social welfare. Second, IP protection should consider the R & D process and patent values to promote innovation. Proposition 3 supports the condition of protecting the IP to avoid technology spillover. Finally, cooperative R&D should be encouraged to improve the likelihood of success.

This study's conclusions will be useful in management. Firms should seek patents with a high technology level because they promote social welfare. Low technology patents may damage the market and reduce social welfare. Therefore, firms need to select patents with a high technology level.

Considering the above analysis, issues for further research are elucidated. To simplify the model, this study assumes that the technology level corresponding to the patent is fixed. Extending this study to the general situation wherein the technology level depends on R & D can be interesting. Moreover, various government strategies can be adopted to support R & D. Combining government policies and elucidating this aspect in detail would be interesting.

Data availability

Data sharing is not applicable to this article as no datasets were generated or analyzed during the current study.

Acknowledgement

This work is partially supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (71771057, 72003044, 72003045) Guangdong Natural Science Foundation for Distinguished Young Scholars (22B1515020034). All authors declare that no conflict of interest exists.

Appendix
Proof of proposition 1

From Eqs. (7) and (11), where c¯≤cK, we obtain

Therefore, c¯≤cKindicates that patent realization promotes total output or consumer surplus. Otherwise, we obtainc¯>cK
Thus, patent realization reduces the total output or consumer surplus.

The relevant conclusions are achieved, and the proof is complete. ▪

Proof of proposition 2

Based on Eq. (14), wherec¯≤cK, the threshold value of the patent price is restated as: V*=[N(A−c¯)N+1−∑j=1j≠KN(A−cj)N+1]2−[(A−cK)−∑j=1N(A−cj)N+1]2=N(cK−c¯)N+1(qK2,*+qK1,*)>0.

Moreover, by Eq. (10), we find that qK2,*increases with the technology level corresponding to this patent and decreases with the competition. Therefore, the patent price's threshold value increases with the technology level and decreases with the competition.

The relevant conclusions are achieved, and the proof is complete. ▪

Proof of Proposition 3

According to Eq. (17), the lowest R&D is [1−exp(−hj(Ij+γI−j))]pp=Ij.This formulation is rewritten as

Considering the ppand I−j, the solution to (A1) is Ij*. Furthermore, (A1) is restated as
(A2) implies
The above inequality arises from the assumption of dhj(x)dx≥0. Moreover, according to the implicit function theorem, when exp(−hj(Ij+γI−j))pp∂hj∂Ij>1, we obtain∂f(Ij,γ)∂Ij>0and the following formulation.
Otherwise, exp(−hj(Ij+γI−j))pp∂hj∂Ij<1, or∂f(Ij,γ)∂Ij<0, the following relationship holds
Therefore, a high level of technology spillover reduces innovative investment underexp(−hj(Ij+γI−j))pp∂hj∂Ij>1. Otherwise, technology spillovers will promote innovative investments.

The relevant conclusions are achieved, and the proof is complete. ▪

References
[Acemoglu et al., 2018]
D. Acemoglu, U. Akcigit, N. Bloom, W.R. Kerr.
Innovation, reallocation and growth.
The American Economic Review, 108 (2018), pp. 3450-3491
[Aghion and Jaravel, 2015]
P. Aghion, X. Jaravel.
Knowledge spillovers, innovation and growth.
The Economic Journal, 125 (2015), pp. 533-573
[Arrow, 1962]
K. Arrow.
Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for inventions.
The rate and direction of inventive activity,
[Che et al., 2021]
Y.-.K. Che, E. Iossa, P. Rey.
Prizes versus contracts as incentives for innovation.
The Review of Economic Studies, 88 (2021), pp. 2149-2178
[Chen et al., 2022]
Z.R. Chen, P.Y. Nie, C. He, H. Zhang.
The impacts of auction methods and market structure on patent portfolio value.
Technology Analysis & Strategic Management, 34 (2022), pp. 1295-1309
[Cockburn et al., 2016]
I.M. Cockburn, J.O. Lanjouw, M. Schankerman.
Patents and the global diffusion of new drugs.
American Economic Review, 106 (2016), pp. 136-164
[Donduran and Ünveren, 2021]
M. Donduran, B. Ünveren.
A Kantian analysis of pricing and R & D.
Review of Industrial Organization, 58 (2021), pp. 1-23
[Fan et al., 2018]
C. Fan, B.H. Jun, E.G. Wolfstetter.
Optimal licensing under incomplete information: The case of the inside patent holder.
Economic Theory, 66 (2018), pp. 979-1005
[Graham, 2020]
B.S. Graham.
Rapid COVID-19 vaccine development.
Science (New York, N.Y.), 368 (2020), pp. 945-946
[Gibert and Newbery, 1982]
R.J. Gibert, D.M.G. Newbery.
Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly.
American Economic Review, 72 (1982), pp. 514-526
[Heaton, 2020]
P.M. Heaton.
The COVID-19 vaccine-development multiverse.
The New England Journal of Medicine, 383 (2020), pp. 1986-1988
[Kogan et al., 2017]
L. Kogan, D. Papanikolaou, A. Seru, N. Stoffman.
Technological innovation, resource allocation, and growth.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132 (2017), pp. 665-712
[Kwon, 2021]
S. Kwon.
The prevalence of weak patents in the United States: A new method to identify weak patents and the implications for patent policy.
Technology in Society, 64 (2021),
[Le et al., 2020]
T.T. Le, Z. Andreadakis, A. Kumar, R.G. Román, S. Tollefsen, M. Saville, et al.
The COVID-19 vaccine development landscape.
Nature Reviews Drug Discovery, 19 (2020), pp. 305-306
[Lim, 1998]
W.S. Lim.
Multistage R&D competition and patent policy.
Journal of Economics, 68 (1998), pp. 153-173
[Minin et al., 2021]
A.D. Minin, L. Dooley, V. Lazzarotti, R. Manzini, L. Mortara, A. Piccaluga.
R&D Management at a time of crisis: What are we learning from the response to the COVID-19 pandemic?.
R & D Management, 51 (2021), pp. 165-168
[Nie and Yang, 2020]
P. Nie, Y. Yang.
Cost-reduction innovation under mixed economy.
Managerial and Decision Economics, 41 (2020), pp. 1195-1201
[Nie et al., 2021]
P. Nie, Z. Chen, C. Wang.
Intellectual property pricing under asymmetric duopoly.
Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services, 58 (2021),
[Nie et al., 2022]
P.Y. Nie, C. Wang, H.X. Wen.
Technology spillover and innovation.
Technology Analysis & Strategic Management, 34 (2022), pp. 210-222
[Nie et al., 2020]
P. Nie, X. Xiao, C. Wang, T. Cui.
Innovation subsidy under duopoly.
Managerial and Decision Economics, 41 (2020), pp. 362-370
[Nie et al., 2023]
P.Y. Nie, C. Wang, H.X. Wen.
Technology standard under cournot competition.
Technology Analysis & Strategic Management, (2023), http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09537325.2021.1969548
[Quintino et al., 2021]
H.M.da S. Quintino, F.S.R. Holanda, F.R. Moura, J.R.de Santana, L.D Vidal.
World efficiency in the potential production of new technologies under intellectual property assets.
Technology in Society, 65 (2021),
[Ribeiro and Shapira, 2020]
B. Ribeiro, P. Shapira.
Private and public values of innovation: A patent analysis of synthetic biology.
Research Policy, 49 (2020),
[Sen and Stamatopoulos, 2019]
D. Sen, G. Stamatopoulos.
Decreasing returns, patent licensing and price-reducing taxes.
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 175 (2019), pp. 291-307
[Song and Zhao, 2021]
Y. Song, M. Zhao.
Dynamic R&D competition under uncertainty and strategic disclosure.
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 181 (2021), pp. 169-210
[Taehyuk and Ilwon, 2021]
K. Taehyuk, S. Ilwon.
Does the protection of first-comer's profit lead more values in the market? ― the case of Korean patent-linkage system.
The Journal of Intellectual Property, 16 (2021), pp. 109-138
[Wang and Nie, 2021]
C. Wang, P.-.Y. Nie.
Analysis of cooperative technological innovation strategy.
Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja, 34 (2021), pp. 1520-1545
[Williams, 2013]
H.L. Williams.
Intellectual property rights and innovation: Evidence from the human genome.
Journal of Political Economy, 121 (2013), pp. 1-27
[Zeng et al., 2014]
J. Zeng, J. Zhang, M.K.-Y. Fung.
Patent length and price regulation in an R&D growth model with monopolistic competition.
Macroeconomic Dynamics, 18 (2014), pp. 1-22

Pu-yan Nie was born in Hunan of China. He received the PhD degree from Chinese Academy of Sciences in 2003. He has been with Guangdong University of Finance & Economics, Guangzhou, China, where he is presently a professor. His-interest currently lies in the field of game theory and industrial economics.

Hong-xing WEN received the PhD degree from China Agricultural University in 2019. He has been with Guangdong University of Finance & Economics, Guangzhou, China, where he is presently an associated professor. His-interest currently lies in the field of development economics and industrial economics.

Chan Wang received the PhD degree from Jinan University in 2017. She has been with Guangdong University of Finance & Economics, Guangzhou, China, where she is presently a full professor. Her interest currently lies in the field of game theory and industrial economics.

Copyright © 2023. The Author(s)
Article options
Tools