Buscar en
Cuadernos de Economía
Toda la web
Inicio Cuadernos de Economía Dollarization and the relationship between EMBI and fundamentals in Latin Americ...
Journal Information
Vol. 40. Issue 112.
Pages 14-30 (January - April 2017)
Share
Share
Download PDF
More article options
Visits
4733
Vol. 40. Issue 112.
Pages 14-30 (January - April 2017)
Article
Full text access
Dollarization and the relationship between EMBI and fundamentals in Latin American Countries
Dolarización y relación entre EMBI y fundamentos en los países latinoamericanos
Visits
4733
María Lorena Mari del Cristoa, Marta Gómez-Puigb,
Corresponding author
marta.gomezpuig@ub.edu

Corresponding author.
a Department of Economics, Universitat de Barcelona, Av. Diagonal 696, 08034 Barcelona, Spain
b Department of Economics and Riskcenter, Universitat de Barcelona, Av. Diagonal 696, 08034 Barcelona, Spain
This item has received
Article information
Abstract
Full Text
Bibliography
Download PDF
Statistics
Figures (3)
Show moreShow less
Tables (10)
Table 1. Annual GDP rate of growth.
Table 2. Annual GDP rate of growth.
Table 3. Variables used in the literature on sovereign returns’ analysis in emerging countries.
Table 4. Variables used in our comparative study.
Table 5. Residual analysis.
Table 6. Johansen tests.
Table 7. Exclusion tests.
Table 8. Long run relationships.
Table 9. Econometric results.
Table 10. Comparative analysis taking only the significant coefficients into account.
Show moreShow less
Abstract

This paper presents empirical evidence on the interrelationship that exists between the evolution of the Emerging Markets Bonds Index (EMBI) and some macroeconomic variables in seven Latin American countries; two of them (Ecuador and Panama), full dollarized. We make use of a Cointegrated Vector framework to analyze the short run effects from 2001 to 2009. The results suggest that EMBI is more stable in dollarized countries and that its evolution influences economic activity in non-dollarized economies; suggesting that investors’ confidence might be higher in dollarized countries where real and financial economic evolution are less vulnerable to external shocks than in non-dollarized ones.

Keywords:
Dollarization
Emerging markets
Latin American countries
Cointegrated VAR
Emerging Markets Bond Index
Exchange rate regime
JEL classification:
C32
E44
F30
Resumen

Este documento aporta la evidencia empírica de la interrelación existente entre la evolución del Indicador de Bonos de Mercados Emergentes y ciertas variables macroeconómicas en 7 países latinoamericanos, de entre los cuales 2 de ellos (Ecuador y Panamá), están plenamente dolarizados. Utilizamos el marco del vector cointegrado para analizar los efectos a corto plazo desde 2001 a 2009. Los resultados indican que el Indicador de Bonos de Mercados Emergentes es más estable en los países dolarizados, y que su evolución ejerce una influencia sobre la actividad económica de las economías no dolarizadas, lo cual apunta a que la confianza de los inversores pudiera ser superior en los países dolarizados, donde la evolución económica real y financiera es menos vulnerable a los shocks externos que en los países no dolarizados.

Palabras clave:
Dolarización
Mercados emergentes
Países latinoamericanos
VAR cointegrado
Indicador de Bonos de Mercados Emergentes
Régimen de tipos de cambio.
Full Text
1Introduction

The global financial and economic crisis of 2008–2009 had a much smaller impact on emerging Latin American markets than on their US and European counterparts. While Latin American countries have continued to grow and do not present major macroeconomic imbalances, the advanced economies still do not present solid recovery (Figs. 1 and 2 jointly with Tables 1 and 2, show the evolution of GDP growth and of the government-debt-to-GDP ratio in the two groups of countries). The marginal exposure of banks in emerging markets to US subprime assets and their governments’ expansive monetary and fiscal policies to stimulate aggregate demand might explain these differences (see Aizenman et al., 2013). However, some authors have analyzed whether exchange rate regimes have played a part.1

Figure 1.

Total Central Government Debt-to-GDP ratio (%). (Latin American countries’ evolution.)

(0.11MB).
Figure 2.

Total Central Government Debt-to-GDP ratio (%). (Evolution of the US and European countries.)

(0.11MB).
Table 1.

Annual GDP rate of growth.

Year  Argentina  Brazil  Colombia  Chile  Mexico  Ecuador  Panama 
2001  −4.45  1.31  1.71  3.35  −0.03  3.97  0.00 
2002  −10.84  2.65  2.48  2.19  0.77  4.11  2.40 
2003  8.76  1.15  3.91  3.92  1.39  2.82  4.68 
2004  9.03  5.71  5.34  6.03  4.21  8.24  7.46 
2005  9.18  3.15  4.71  5.60  3.07  5.32  6.94 
2006  8.51  3.95  6.68  4.58  4.97  4.33  8.44 
2007  8.65  6.09  6.90  4.53  3.22  2.07  12.57 
2008  6.71  5.17  3.59  3.67  1.37  6.33  10.10 
2009  0.86  −0.33  1.61  −0.99  −4.74  0.63  3.86 
2010  9.16  7.53  3.97  5.73  5.20  3.59  7.44 
2011  8.86  2.73  6.67  5.89  3.83  7.75  10.82 
2012  1.88  1.02  4.20  5.50  3.94  5.11  10.93 
Table 2.

Annual GDP rate of growth.

Year  Belgium  France  Greece  Ireland  Italy  Portugal  United States 
2001  0.80  1.83  4.19  4.98  1.86  1.97  0.94 
2002  1.35  0.92  3.43  5.41  0.45  0.76  1.77 
2003  0.80  0.89  5.94  3.72  −0.04  −0.91  2.79 
2004  3.27  2.54  4.36  4.19  1.73  1.56  3.79 
2005  1.75  1.82  2.28  6.08  0.93  0.77  3.35 
2006  2.66  2.46  5.50  5.50  2.19  1.44  2.66 
2007  2.88  2.28  3.53  4.97  1.68  2.36  1.78 
2008  0.98  −0.08  −0.21  −2.16  −1.15  −0.01  −0.29 
2009  −2.80  −3.14  −3.13  −6.38  −5.49  −2.90  −2.80 
2010  2.32  1.72  −4.94  −1.06  1.72  1.93  2.50 
2011  1.76  2.02  −7.10  2.16  0.47  −1.25  1.84 
2012  −0.13  0.01  −6.37  0.15  −2.53  −3.22  2.77 

This paper has two main objectives. The first is to empirically investigate the role of fundamentals in the reduced vulnerability to shocks observed in the bond markets of seven Latin American countries, and how this reduced vulnerability has in turn affected macroeconomic fundamentals. The second is to determine whether there are any differences between countries that can be attributed to their exchange rate regime. Specifically, we aim to compare countries with and without a fully-dollarized economy. To this end, we empirically assess the relationship between key economic factors such as the external debt-to-exports ratio and inflation, and the Emerging Markets Bonds Index (EMBI)2 during the sample period 2001–2009. In the second stage of the study, we aim to establish whether there are relevant differences in the two groups of countries (dollarized and non-dollarized economies).

A review of the empirical literature shows that our first question has usually been approached through an analysis of the main determinants of country risk premium.3 For instance, Edwards (1986) uses data on yields of 167 bonds floated by 13 Least Developed Countries (LDC) between 1976 and 1980 to analyze the factors that determine the country risk premium. He presents evidence that bond spreads depend positively on the countries’ level of indebtedness and negatively on the level of investment they undertake. Nogués and Grandes (2001), focusing on monthly data for Argentina between 1994 and 1998 and estimating its econometric model by OLS, conclude that endogenous factors such as the external debt-to-exports ratio, the fiscal deficit, growth expectations, contagion effects or political noise are the determinants of Argentina's country risk. Gónzalez-Rozada and Levy Yeyati (2008), however, estimating panel error-correction models of emerging spreads on high-yield corporate bonds in developed markets and international rates (US Treasury bills) and using high frequency (monthly, weekly and daily) data from 33 emerging economies, find that global (exogenous) factors explain over 50 per cent of the long run volatility of emerging market spreads.

To sum up, the country risk premium has generally been proxied in the literature by sovereign spreads. Specifically, the spread of JP Morgan's EMBI Global index over US Treasuries bills in Latin America countries is the most important reference for prospective investors in this area.

The research so far on the determinants of country risk can be classified in three groups.4 First, certain authors have found a significant correlation between macroeconomic-political variables and the risk premium (Hoti and McAller, 2004; Baldacci et al., 2008; Aizenman et al., 2013). Authors in the second group have emphasized the effect of exogenous factors (global factors, contagion effects, capital flows or “investor's sentiment”) on risk premium (Eichengreen and Mody, 1998; Kamin and Von Kleist, 1999; Schuknecht et al., 2009, 2010). Finally, authors in the third group relate country risk and the exchange rate regime. They consider that investors want to know two major components of country risk premium: the currency premium, which can be measured as the yield spread between non-dollar-denominated and US dollar-denominated sovereign debt of the same borrowing country, and the credit premium, measured as the yield spread between the dollar-denominated sovereign debt of the emerging country and US Treasury bills. There is a certain consensus inside the third group of authors that dollarization and hard pegs would substantially reduce the country risk of emerging countries (Domowitz et al., 1998; Rubinstein, 1999; Schmukler, 2002).

The aim of this paper is to contribute to this branch of the literature by examining the impact of macroeconomic fundamentals on risk premium and vice versa, since movements in government bond yields may have significant macroeconomic consequences, (see Caceres et al., 2010).

The literature on the determinants of EMBI in specific Latin American countries is still scarce. Fracasso (2007), a good reference for Brazil (he shows that foreign investors’ appetite for risk impacts substantially on EMBI spreads)5; Nogués and Grandes (2001) for Argentina, who highlight that devaluation risk elimination may not have a statistically significant impact on country risk (other macroeconomic variables such as the external debt-to-exports ratio and growth expectations present a higher impact); Vargas et al. (2012), for Colombia, who present evidence that improvement of fiscal variables reduces the sovereign risk premium; López Herrera et al. (2013) for Mexico, who find long-run relationships between domestic macroeconomic variables and the Mexican EMBI; Lindao Jurado and Erazo Blum (2009) for Ecuador who conclude that debt and the inflation are the most important factors for explaining its country risk; Délano and Selaive (2005), who examine Chilean's EMBI behaviour and conclude that approximately 25% of the variability of the sovereign spread is due to global factors, and finally the IMF (2010) which emphasizes that achieving investment grade lowers Panamanian debt spreads by over 140 basis points.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the theoretical framework while Section 3 outlines the data and the econometric model used in the empirical analysis. Section 4 reports the main empirical results, comparing dollarized and non-dollarized countries. Finally, Section 5 presents the main conclusions.

2Country risk and EMBI determinants2.1The equilibrium condition for a risk-neutral lender

Following Edwards (1986), in an emerging or developing country that cannot affect the world interest rate, the cost of external funds is formed by two concepts: (1) the risk-free world interest rate (i*) and (2) a country risk premium (s) related to the probability of default perceived by the lender (p). In the case of a one-period loan, where in case of default the lender loses both the principal and the interest, the equilibrium condition for a risk-neutral lender is:

From here, the country risk premium is:

where k=1+i*.

Since the probability of default depends positively on the debt-to-GDP ratio, as the seminal article by Eaton and Gersowitz (1981) demonstrated, the country then faces an upwards-sloping supply curve for foreign funds. As the probability of default approaches one, the country risk premium approaches infinity and a credit ceiling will be reached. The country in question will have difficulties gaining access to the world's credit market. If the variables that comprise the probability of default perceived by lenders were known, the countries might be able to improve them in order to reduce it to zero.

According to Edwards (1986), p has the following logistic function:

where Xi are the determinants of the sovereign risk premium and βi are the corresponding coefficients. Combining (2) and (3), taking logarithms and adding a random disturbance ¿, the equation to be estimated is:

The signs of this equation change slightly if the model is described in terms of returns. Transforming Eq. (1), we obtain:

where r* is the risk-free world return and s represents, this time, the reduction in terms of return on the bond investment, and k*=1+r*. Our Eq. (4) then only changes the signs:

Moving terms, we obtain the emerging country return depending on the same determinants of country risk:

2.2Determinants of each country return index

Both theoretical and empirical studies have highlighted a large number of variables that may affect the evolution of government debt returns in emerging countries.6 We can split these variables into three groups: economic-financial, socio-political, and global factors.

Table 3 details some of the variables used in the empirical literature by a wide range of authors to explain the determinants of government debt returns in emerging countries, whilst Table 4 describes the variables used in our model.

Table 3.

Variables used in the literature on sovereign returns’ analysis in emerging countries.

Variable  Description/authors 
Economic and financial variables
Debt-to-GDP ratio  The most important variable, since in most theoretical models of foreign borrowing it is included as an important triggering factor to borrowers to default (Eaton and Gersowitz, 1981; Edwards, 1986, 1986). It has also been included in empirical studies (Aizenman et al., 2013; Eichengreen and Mody, 1998). 
International reserves to GNP or GDP  Measures the solvency held by a country. (See Edwards, 1986; Aizenman et al., 2013; Rowland and Torres, 2004, to name a few). 
Investment-to-GNP/GDP ratio; GDP per capita growth; Industrial production.  These variables capture the country's prospects for future growth. There are other variables used in the literature, though, such as the growth rate measured by the difference between the logs of GDP in time t and t1. (See Nogués and Grandes, 2001; Edwards, 1986 or Aizenman et al., 2013
Current account-to-GNP/GDP ratio  Solvency variables. (See Edwards, 1986; Nogués and Grandes, 2001; or Aizenman et al., 2013). 
External debt service- to- exports ratio; External debt- to- GDP ratio; External debt- to- exports.  These variables capture the intertemporal liquidity situation of a country. (Edwards, 1986; Nogués and Grandes, 2001; Aizenman et al., 2013; Rowland and Torres, 2004). 
Imports-to- GNP ratio; Trade openness (Exports plus Imports) % of GDP; Terms of trade  These variables gauge the importance of trade. (See Edwards, 1986; Aizenman et al., 2013; or Baldacci et al., 2008
Index of real effective exchange rate  See Edwards (1986) or Gónzalez-Rozada and Levy Yeyati (2008)
Fiscal balance- to- GDP ratio.  This variable measures the country's fiscal sustainability. (See Nogués and Grandes, 2001; Gónzalez-Rozada and Levy Yeyati, 2008; or Baldacci et al., 2008). 
Inflation rate  See Baldacci et al. (2008) or Aizenman et al. (2013)
Social and political variables
Political noise  Nogués and Grandes (2001) focused on Argentina and tested the political noise associated with the resignation of the Minister Cavallo through a dummy variable that took the value 1 in the period of uncertainty that led to his resignation. 
Global factors
External financial shocks  Nogués and Grandes (2001) capture them using the rate of the 30-year US Treasury bonds, whilst Gónzalez-Rozada and Levy Yeyati (2008) use the 10-year US Treasury rate. 
Contagion effects  They can be captured either by dummies or by variables such as other countries’ returns. For instance, Nogués and Grandes (2001) included the JP Morgan Price index of Mexican bonds to measure its relationship with the country risk of Argentina. They expected that the historical similarities (in terms of economic policy and response to external shocks) between Mexico and Argentina would result in a similar behaviour of their governments’ returns, beyond fundamental-based reasons. 
Market sentiment  Diaz Weigel and Gemmill (2006) analyze a sample of emerging countries using variables such as US and regional stock returns or oil prices as proxies of global factors and market sentiment. 
Table 4.

Variables used in our comparative study.

Variable  Observations  Source 
LEMBI_country  Monthly average has been calculated from daily reported JP Morgan EMBI.  Datastream 
LEAI, LIAI, LII, LIPI, LREV (These variables represent growth expectations. The variable used depends on data availability in each country).  LEAI: Economic activity index in Argentina, Colombia and Ecuador.
LIAI: Industrial activity index in Mexico.
LII: Industrial Index in Brazil.
LIPI: Industrial production index in Chile.
LREV: Revenues from taxes levied in the Panama Canal. 
Argentina: Statistical National Institute (www.indec.mecon.ar)
Brazil: Brazilian Statistical and Geographical Institute (www.ibge.gov.br)
Colombia: Central Bank of Colombia Republic (www.banrep.gov.co)
Chile: National Statistical Institute (www.ine.cl)
Ecuador: Central Bank (www.bce.ec)
Mexico: National Statistical and Geographical Institute (www. Inegi.org.mx)
Panama: National Contraloria (www.contraloria.gob.pa
INF  Inflation statistics in the case of Ecuador, but in the rest of the countries the difference in the Consumer Prices Index is used  Ecuador: Central Bank
Rest of countries: ECLAC. 
LDEBT_X  External debt-to-exports ratio  Economic Commission of the Latin American and Caribbean countries (ECLAC). 
3Data and empirical approach3.1Data and variables

Table 4 provides the description of the variables along with the data sources. We included four endogenous variables in our econometric model. The EMBI (with its monthly average calculated from daily data, in order to eliminate its heteroscedasticity and because the rest of variables are available at this frequency), along with variables that are only reported monthly, such as the Economic Activity Index (eai). This variable was used to measure the growth perspective in the case of Argentina, Colombia and Ecuador, while the growth perspective was proxied by the Industrial Activity Index (iai) in Mexico, the Industrial Index (ii) in Brazil, the Industrial Production Index (ipi) in Chile and, finally, the revenues from taxes to cross the Canal in the case of Panama.7 In Panama we used this variable because all the other sectors of its economy depend on Canal activities, as do other markets such as the labour market. The other monthly variables are the inflation rate (inf), which was has been calculated from the Consumer Price Index in all the countries, except in Ecuador where it was directly recorded, and the external debt-to-exports ratio (debt_x), which captures the current account solvency of emerging countries.

The impact of global risk factors will be captured through the inclusion of dummies.

3.2Econometric approach: identification of the short run structure in the Cointegrated VAR (CVAR)

Consider the Cointegrated VAR model in the so-called reduced form representation:

Pre-multiplying (8) with a non-singular p×p matrix A0, we obtain the so-called structural form representation:

where A1=A0Г1, a=A0α, vt=A0¿t

The short run equations consist of p equations between p current variables, Δxt, p(k1) lagged variables (Δxti, i=1, …, k1), and r lagged equilibrium errors, (βc)′xt−1. Identification of the r long run relationships requires at least r−1 restrictions on each relationship, while identification of the simultaneous short run structure of the p equations requires at least p−1 restrictions on each equation.

Keeping the properly identified cointegrating relationships fixed at their estimated values, i.e. by treating (βc)′xt−1 as predetermined stationary regressors, as in the case of Δxti, it is easier to identify the simultaneous short run structure. We identify the long run relationships first, and then the short run adjustment parameters.

The unrestricted short run reduced form model is identified exactly by the p1 zero restrictions on each row of A0=I. Further zero restrictions on Г1, α and Φ are over-identifying. Thus, the process of identification consists firstly in individually testing whether all lagged variables, the long run structure, and dummy variables are statistically significant in the system. The next step is to remove the non-significant variables from the system, so that the generally identified model only contains significant coefficients. The significant coefficients will identify the short run adjustment parameters and the long run relationships that affect the dependent variables of our simultaneous equations system which is estimated by maximum likelihood.8

4Empirical results4.1Econometric steps

First, we estimated an unrestricted VAR for each country with the following structure: Xt=[EMBI, eai, inf, debt_x]. Previously, all the variables were transformed into logarithms except inflation; recall from Section 3.1 that the variable capturing the growth expectations (eai) changes depending on the country in question. Second, we carried out the residual analysis shown properly in Table 5

Table 5.

Residual analysis.

(a) Argentina
Tests for autocorrelation and lag length determination
Model  k  T  Regr  Log-Lik  SC  H-Q  LM (k) 
VAR(2)  102  20  1060.174  −17.160  −18.385  0.582 
VAR(1)  102  16  1032.474  −17.343  −18.323  0.000 
Univariate statistics
  ARCH(2)  Normality  R-squared 
DLEMBI_M_ARG  3.732 [0.155]  5.806 [0.055]  0.697 
DLEAI  0.252 [0.881]  0.204 [0.903]  0.945 
DINF  12.131 [0.002]  4.875 [0.087]  0.852 
DLDEBT_X  1.473 [0.479]  17.219 [0.000]  0.416 
(b) Brazil
Tests for autocorrelation and lag length determination
Model  k  T  Regr  Log-Lik  SC  H-Q  LM (k) 
VAR(3)  102  13  1052.667  −18.283  −19.079  0.212 
VAR(2)  102  1031.318  −18.590  −19.141  0.031 
VAR(1)  102  1018.918  −19.072  −19.378  0.151 
Univariate statistics
  ARCH(3)  Normality  R-squared 
DLEMBI_M_BRA  6.537 [0.088]  7.799 [0.020]  0.353 
DLII  0.337 [0.953]  0.048 [0.976]  0.417 
DINF  1.399 [0.706]  2.892 [0.236]  0.516 
DLDEBT_X  5.180 [0.159]  1.851 [0.396]  0.336 
(c) Colombia
Tests for autocorrelation and lag length determination
Model  k  T  Regr  Log-Lik  SC  H-Q  LM (k) 
VAR(2)  102  20  946.132  −14.924  −16.149  0.722 
VAR(1)  102  16  909.039  −14.922  −15.902  0.000 
Univariate statistics
  ARCH(2)  Normality  R-squared 
DLEMBI_CO  2.497 [0.287]  5.191 [0.075]  0.501 
DLDEBT_X  1.316 [0.518]  2.178 [0.337]  0.553 
DLIMACO  1.075 [0.584]  9.972 [0.007]  0.887 
DINF  0.783 [0.676]  1.328 [0.515]  0.661 
(d) Chile
Tests for autocorrelation and lag length determination
Model  k  T  Regr  Log-Lik  SC  H-Q  LM (k) 
VAR(3)  102  24  1133.568  −17.874  −19.344  0.138 
VAR(2)  102  20  1107.698  −18.092  −19.317  0.004 
VAR(1)  102  16  1082.957  −18.332  −19.313  0.001 
Univariate statistics
  ARCH(3)  Normality  R-squared 
DLEMBI_CH  6.776 [0.079]  1.367 [0.505]  0.632 
DLIPI  1.186 [0.756]  0.389 [0.823]  0.858 
DINF  0.208 [0.976]  2.704 [0.259]  0.609 
DLDEBT_X  0.848 [0.838]  0.252 [0.882]  0.608 
(e) Mexico
Tests for autocorrelation and lag length determination
Model  k  T  Regr  Log-Lik  SC  H-Q  LM (k) 
VAR(4)  102  17  773.042  −12.074  −13.116  0.189 
VAR(3)  102  13  748.491  −12.318  −13.115  0.002 
VAR(2)  102  714.167  −12.371  −12.922  0.000 
VAR(1)  102  693.836  −12.698  −13.004  0.003 
Univariate statistics
  ARCH(4)  Normality  R-squared 
DLEMBI_MX  8.903 [0.064]  3.879 [0.144]  0.654 
DIAI  16.944 [0.002]  1.125 [0.570]  0.547 
DINF  11.197 [0.024]  2.921 [0.232]  0.558 
DLDEBT_X  7.688 [0.104]  3.403 [0.182]  0.409 
(f) Ecuador
Tests for autocorrelation and lag length determination
Model  k  T  Regr  Log-Lik  SC  H-Q  LM (k) 
VAR(2)  139  20  1978.853  −25.633  −26.635  0.081 
VAR(1)  139  16  1931.693  −25.522  −26.324  0.000 
Univariate statistics
  ARCH(2)  Normality  R-squared 
DLEMBI_M_EC  9.820 [0.007]  12.068 [0.002]  0.741 
DLEAI  1.248 [0.536]  0.021 [0.990]  0.663 
DINF  2.059 [0.357]  0.065 [0.968]  0.775 
DLDEBT_X  4.122 [0.127]  2.100 [0.350]  0.469 
(g) Panama
Tests for autocorrelation and lag length determination
Model  k  T  Regr  Log-Lik  SC  H-Q  LM (k) 
VAR(2)  102  20  1039.011  −16.745  −17.970  0.589 
VAR(1)  102  16  1016.394  −17.027  −18.007  0.029 
Univariate statistics
  ARCH(2)  Normality  R-squared 
DLEMBI_M_PANA  1.942 [0.379]  3.805 [0.149]  0.614 
DLEREV_C  0.118 [0.943]  1.647 [0.439]  0.745 
DINF  3.593 [0.166]  0.162 [0.922]  0.634 
DLDEBT_X  0.335 [0.846]  2.609 [0.271]  0.617 

Here we detail the dummies included for each country:

Argentina: The dummy dum0111p (2001:11) takes into account the significant fall in the Global EMBI due to the currency crisis sparked by Argentina's abandoning of the currency board, following public debt default.9 Dum0202p and dum0204p variables capture the consequences of devaluation that generated inflation pressures (ECLAC, 2002). The dum0504p was included to normalize debt_x residuals since at that date external debt experienced a sharp decrease when Argentina launched a debt exchange in 2005.10 Brazil: dum0211p is included to normalize the debt_x residuals. After the 1999 devaluation on the public debt denominated in US dollars, Brazil's debt increased substantially, reaching 50% of total public debt at the end of 2002.11 Colombia: The objective of dum0405p is to normalize the EMBI residuals; three dummies dum0901p, dum0904p and dum0907p represent the impact of the 2008–2009 global crisis on Colombia's economic activity (ECLAC, 2009). Chile: dum0405p which normalizes the EMBI residuals and the dum0901p which normalizes the economic activity variable (ipi) are incorporated in the analysis. Mexico: dum0405p is also included in order to eliminate the outliers of the EMBI's residuals. Ecuador: Five permanent dummies need to be included. Whilst dum0906p is related to Ecuador default in 2009,12 dum0811p is introduced to jointly explain the debt_x and the EMBI evolution. The rest of dummies are dum0109p and dum0301p which are needed to normalize inflation residuals.13 Panama: The dum0401p normalizes residuals of inflation. Prices decreased in the first quarter of 2004, but the trend reverted afterward due to the rise in oil prices and other import products (ECLAC, 2004).

The dum0810p (along with dum0811p only for Ecuador) is common to all the endogenous variables since it is related to the start of the world financial crisis (the US financial institution Lehman Brothers collapsed in September 2008 and affected the EMBI evolution of all emerging countries included in this study). Dummies such as dum0405p and dum0901p might explain contagion effects between Chile, Colombia and Mexico.14 Dum0405p captures the incidence of global factors such as a fall in international interest rates, which we can proxy using the US Treasury 10-year yield15 (Fig. 3 shows that Treasury bonds yields went down in 2004:05).

Figure 3.

US Treasury 10 year bond rate evolution (Monthly data 2001–2009).

(0.09MB).

Following Eichengreen and Mody (1998), we assume that the relationship between the US Treasury bond rates and emerging bond prices is explained in terms of demand.16 On the demand side, when Treasury bonds rates go up (their prices go down), there will be a tendency among investors to substitute emerging bonds by US Treasury bonds, and so the EMBI price falls. Finally, dummy dum0901p represents the vulnerability of Chile and Colombia with respect to the other countries included in the sample during the global economic crisis of 2008–2009.

Third, we determined the rank of cointegration; Table 6 shows the results of Johansen's (1996) test, which concludes that all the countries reflect the presence of just one cointegrated vector; so the rank of their long run matrix is equal to 1 (with the exception of Panama, which matrix's rank is 2).

Table 6.

Johansen tests.

pr  r  Eig. value  Trace  Trace  Frac95  P-value  P-Value  pr  r  Eig. value  Trace  Trace  Frac95  P-value  P-value 
(a) Argentina(b) Brazil
0.253  57.195  53.353  47.707  0.004  0.013  0.356  84.746  77.834  63.659  0.000  0.002 
0.124  26.531  25.002  29.804  0.117  0.166  0.226  39.058  36.872  42.770  0.115  0.178 
0.106  12.589  11.831  15.408  0.131  0.167  0.112  12.412  11.780  25.731  0.782  0.824 
0.007  0.781  0.714  3.841  0.377  0.398  0.001  0.114  0.110  12.448  1.000  1.000 
(c) Colombia(d) Chile
0.263  51.127  49.007  47.707  0.022  0.037  0.271  52.125  49.204  47.707  0.017  0.035 
0.138  19.146  18.491  29.804  0.493  0.540  0.131  19.239  18.217  29.804  0.487  0.560 
0.029  3.502  3.242  15.408  0.932  0.947  0.037  4.696  4.139  15.408  0.837  0.886 
0.004  0.454  0.343  3.841  0.500  0.558  0.007  0.741  0.549  3.841  0.389  0.459 
(e) Mexico(f) Ecuador
0.375  74.024  67.332  47.707  0.000  0.000  0.289  66.145  61.757  47.707  0.000  0.001 
0.141  25.549  23.741  29.804  0.147  0.219  0.195  29.970  28.117  29.804  0.048  0.078 
0.089  9.849  8.448  15.408  0.298  0.426  0.064  6.956  6.563  15.408  0.589  0.634 
0.003  0.303  0.283  3.841  0.582  0.595  0.000  0.001  0.001  3.841  0.970  0.972 
(g) Panama               
0.323  83.576  79.508  47.707  0.000  0.000                 
0.235  42.641  40.886  29.804  0.001  0.001                 
0.128  14.546  13.868  15.408  0.068  0.086                 
0.001  0.104  0.099  3.841  0.747  0.754                 

Fourth, we test and impose over-identifying restrictions on the long run structure (beta vectors) in order to have only significant coefficients. Table 7 shows the tests of exclusion for the seven countries, and Table 8 the final cointegration relationships for each of the countries. These long run relationships will be added as another predetermined variable into the simultaneous equation system and, along with dummies and lagged differenced variables, we will test whether their coefficients are significant or not.17

Table 7.

Exclusion tests.

(a) Argentina(b) Brazil
r  DFG  5%CV  LEMBI_M_ARG  LEAI  INF  LDEBT_X  r  DFG  5%CV  LEMBI_M_BRA  LII  INF  LDEBT_X 
3.841  0.177 [0.674]  0.160 [0.689]  46.649 [0.000]  0.148 [0.701]  3.841  1.682 [0.195]  8.402 [0.004]  9.067 [0.003]  2.262 [0.133] 
5.991  15.169 [0.001]  1.422 [0.491]  61.128 [0.000]  3.340 [0.188]  5.991  4.477 [0.107]  21.536 [0.000]  23.366 [0.000]  5.754 [0.056] 
7.815  21.412 [0.000]  8.798 [0.032]  64.226 [0.000]  11.312 [0.010]  7.815  12.327 [0.006]  32.972 [0.000]  34.786 [0.000]  15.161 [0.002] 
(c) Colombia(d) Chile
r  DFG  5%CV  LEMBI_CO  LIMACO  INF  LDEBT_X  r  DFG  5%CV  LEMBI_CH  LIPI  INF  LDEBT_X 
3.841  6.244 [0.012]  11.050 [0.001]  2.505 [0.113]  3.386 [0.066]  3.841  3.280 [0.070]  10.785 [0.001]  12.279 [0.000]  4.749 [0.029] 
5.991  6.793 [0.033]  18.160 [0.000]  17.016 [0.000]  3.791 [0.150]  5.991  5.856 [0.053]  16.712 [0.000]  18.250 [0.000]  8.666 [0.013] 
7.815  18.919 [0.000]  30.095 [0.000]  29.917 [0.000]  15.027 [0.002]  7.815  8.233 [0.041]  19.840 [0.000]  21.572 [0.000]  12.050 [0.007] 
(e) Mexico(f) Ecuador
r  DFG  5%CV  LEMBI_MX  IAI  INF  LDEBT_X  r  DFG  5%CV  LEMBI_M_EC  LEAI  INF  LDEBT_X 
3.841  0.002 [0.961]  0.015 [0.904]  32.296 [0.000]  0.726 [0.394]  3.841  1.391 [0.238]  0.019 [0.891]  32.046 [0.000]  0.176 [0.675] 
5.991  1.885 [0.390]  0.048 [0.976]  38.251 [0.000]  4.239 [0.120]  5.991  1.429 [0.490]  10.899 [0.004]  40.450 [0.000]  9.598 [0.008] 
7.815  9.470 [0.024]  8.479 [0.037]  47.469 [0.000]  13.480 [0.004]  7.815  10.337 [0.016]  20.355 [0.000]  47.864 [0.000]  15.872 [0.001] 
(g) Panama
r  DFG  5%CV  LEMBI_PANA  IREV_C  INF  LDEBT_X 
3.841  1.318 [0.251]  2.971 [0.085]  11.776 [0.001]  10.982 [0.001] 
5.991  11.760 [0.003]  13.278 [0.001]  20.549 [0.000]  15.019 [0.001] 
7.815  25.313 [0.000]  25.599 [0.000]  34.818 [0.000]  29.224 [0.001] 

Note: LR-test, Chi-square (r), P-values in brackets.

Table 8.

Long run relationships.

Country  CI(1)  CI(2) 
Argentina  Inf   
Brazil  Lii0.18221*Inf+0.1918*LDebt_X   
Colombia  LEmbi_co1.0232*LIMACO2.4449*Inf   
Chile  LEmbi_ch+0.07898*LDebt_X0.2549*Inf   
Mexico  Inf   
Ecuador  Inf   
Panama  −0.79176*Lrev_c+LEmbi_pana  0.61532*Inf+LDebt_X0.44483*LRev_c 

Finally as a fifth step, we test the CVAR model as a simultaneous equation system. Its results are summarized in Table 9a–g. We present the significance of the t-values for the different coefficients in order to highlight the differences between the countries18 – specifically, between dollarized and non-dollarized countries.

Table 9.

Econometric results.

(a) Argentina
Variable equation  DLEmbi_arg  DLeai  Dinf  DLDebt_X 
DLEmbi_arg_1  0.4745 (0.0729) [6.51]  0.055 (0.0178) [3.11]  0.0650 (0.2797) [0.233]  −0.2536 (0.084) [−3.02] 
DLeai_1  0.2267 (0.4613) [0.492]  −0.0911 (0.1127) [−0.809]  1.5977 (1.769) [0.903]  0.386 (0.5317) [0.727] 
Dinf_1  −0.00607 (0.0142) [−0.426]  −0.0024 (0.0034) [−0.697]  −0.1776 (0.054) [−3.35]  0.0097 (0.0164) [0.593] 
DLDebt_X_1  0.1185 (0.0876) [1.40]  0.0264 (0.0207) [1.28]  −0.3997 (0.3251) [−1.23]  −0.1450 (0.097) [−1.48] 
CI(1)_1*  0.00036 (0.0111) [0.0329]  0.00144 (0.00272) [0.531]  −0.3642 (0.0427) [−8.53]  −0.0088 (0.0128) [−0.69] 
Dum0111p  −0.2780 (0.0689) [−4.03]  −0.0154 (0.01683) [−0.917]  −0.1857 (0.2643) [−0.703]  −0.0372 (0.079) [−0.469] 
Dum0202p  0.0959 (0.07146) [1.34]  0.0027 (0.0174) [0.155]  1.2090 (0.2740) [4.41]  −0.0299 (0.082) [−0.364] 
Dum0204p  −0.0425 (0.0707) [−0.602]  0.022 (0.01728) [1.30]  3.9607 (0.2713) [14.6]  0.0106 (0.081) [0.13] 
Dum0504p  −0.1002 (0.0694) [−1.44]  0.0100 (0.0169) [0.595]  −0.5195 (0.2663) [−1.95]  −0.409 (0.080) [−5.12] 
Dum0810p  −0.4681 (0.0688) [−6.80]  0.0077 (0.01682) [0.459]  0.0541 (0.2641) [0.205]  0.073 (0.079) [0.92] 
(b) Brazil
Variable equation  DLEmbi_br  DLii  Dinf  DLDebt__X 
DLEmbi_br_1  0.2413 (0.0968) [2.49]  −0.3561 (0.1317) [−2.70]  −0.3595 (0.3619) [−0.993]  0.6114 (0.2537) [2.41] 
DLEmbi_br_2  −0.0300 (0.0993) [−0.303]  0.1743 (0.1352) [1.29]  −0.4834 (0.3714) [−1.30]  0.1667 (0.2604) [0.640] 
DLii_1  0.1173 (0.0988) [1.19]  −0.0219 (0.1345) [−0.163]  −1.206 (0.3696) [−3.26]  −0.7832 (0.2591) [−3.02] 
DLii_2  0.0645 (0.0899) [0.718]  0.4152 (0.1224) [3.39]  −0.3957 (0.3363) [−1.18]  −0.9867 (0.2358) [−4.19] 
Dinf_1  −0.0212 (0.0225) [−0.942]  −0.0352 (0.0307) [−1.15]  −0.2212 (0.0843) [−2.62]  0.03738 (0.0591) [0.632] 
Dinf_2  0.0392 (0.0208) [1.89]  −0.0917 (0.0282) [−3.25]  −0.1435 (0.0777) [−1.85]  0.0879 (0.0545) [1.61] 
DLDebt_X_1  0.0171 (0.0451) [0.379]  −0.0441 (0.0614) [−0.719]  −0.0632 (0.1688) [−0.375]  −0.4393 (0.1183) [−3.71] 
DLDebt_X_2  0.0655 (0.0444) [1.48]  0.0508 (0.0604) [0.841]  0.0320 (0.1662) [0.193]  −0.2745 (0.1165) [−2.36] 
CI(1)_1*  −0.0612 (0.074) [−0.819]  −0.4247 (0.1018) [−4.17]  1.104 (0.2797) [3.95]  0.6363 (0.1961) [3.25] 
Dum0211p  0.1891 (0.0453) [4.17]  −0.0553 (0.0617) [−0.898]  1.1154 (0.1696) [6.58]  0.2762 (0.1189) [2.32] 
Dum0810p  −0.1312 (0.0433) [−3.03]  0.0228 (0.0589) [0.387]  0.0279 (0.1621) [0.172]  0.0769 (0.1137) [0.677] 
(c) Colombia
Variable equation  DLEmbi_co  DLIMACO  Dinf  DLDebt_X 
DLEmbi_co_1  0.1520 (0.095) [1.60]  1.1126 (0.5134) [2.17]  −1.15585 (0.7058) [−1.64]  −0.4547 (0.3327) [−1.37] 
DLIMACO_1  −0.01669 (0.008016) [−2.08]  −0.5392 (0.0433) [−12.5]  0.037718 (0.05953) [0.634]  −0.02614 (0.02806) [−0.932] 
Dinf_1  0.01621 (0.01507) [1.08]  0.1390 (0.06141) [1.71]  −0.184651 (0.1119) [−1.65]  −0.03471 (0.0527) [−0.658] 
DLDebt_X_1  0.01487 (0.02810) [0.501]  −0.3494 (0.1518) [−2.30]  −0.097537 (0.2087) [−0.467]  −0.4635 (0.09839) [−4.71] 
CI(1)_1*  −0.00061 (0.00306) [−0.202]  0.1247 (0.01655) [7.54]  0.03288 (0.02275) [1.45]  −0.005683 (0.01072) [−0.53] 
Dum0405p  −0.1057 (0.02889) [−3.66]  0.02470 (0.1561) [0.158]  0.16086 (0.2145) [0.75]  0.00572 (0.1011) [0.0566] 
Dum0810p  −0.1548 (0.03011) [−5.14]  −0.3675 (0.1626) [−2.26]  0.5895 (0.2236) [2.64]  0.028015 (0.1054) [0.266] 
Dum0901p  −0.00769 (0.030) [−0.255]  −0.8094 (0.1631) [−4.96]  −0.1852 (0.2243) [−0.826]  0.1348 (0.1057) [1.28] 
Dum0904p  0.02359 (0.02929) [0.805]  −1.4419 (0.1582) [−9.11]  −0.02224 (0.2175) [−0.102]  0.1485 (0.1025) [1.45] 
Dum0907p  −0.01486 (0.03016) [−0.493]  −2.3418 (0.1629) [−14.4]  0.15916 (0.2240) [0.711]  0.00464 (0.1056) [0.0440] 
(d) Chile
Variable equation  DLEmbi_ch  DLipi  Dinf  DLDebt_X 
DLEmbi_ch_1  0.2574 (0.0855) [3.01]  0.2394 (0.1278) [1.87]**  −0.0509 (1.294) [−0.039]  −0.8188 (0.4075) [−2.01] 
DLEmbi_ch_2  −0.2627 (0.08522) [−3.08]  −0.077 (0.1274) [−0.611]  3.3522 (1.29) [2.60]  −0.5122 (0.4061) [−1.26] 
DLipi_1  −0.04337 (0.06672) [−0.650]  −0.3102 (0.099) [−3.11]  −0.8168 (1.010) [−0.809]  0.0184 (0.3179) [0.0582] 
DLipi_2  0.0069 (0.0635) [0.109]  −0.02408 (0.09504) [−0.253]  −2.6025 (0.9622) [−2.70]  −0.153 (0.3030) [−0.508] 
Dinf_1  −0.0024 (0.0068) [−0.362]  −0.0049 (0.010) [−0.481]  −0.2602 (0.1042) [−2.50]  −0.054 (0.03281) [−1.65] 
Dinf_2  −0.001122 (0.0067) [−0.166]  0.006 (0.01011) [0.665]  −0.3613 (0.1023) [−3.53]  −0.0704 (0.03222) [−2.19] 
DLDebt_X_1  −0.0069 (0.02465) [−0.280]  −0.0200 (0.0368) [−0.545]  −0.1078 (0.3731) [−0.289]  −0.6481 (0.1175) [−5.52] 
DLDebt_X_2  −0.0063 (0.0244) [−0.261]  0.03496 (0.0364) [0.959]  −0.1842 (0.3692) [−0.499]  −0.3492 (0.1163) [−3.00] 
CI(1)_1*  −0.007875 (0.0080) [−0.976]  0.0018 (0.0120) [0.155]  0.0939 (0.1222) [0.769]  −0.0318 (0.0384) [−0.829] 
Dum0405p  −0.0995 (0.02314) [−4.30]  −0.0123 (0.0345) [−0.357]  0.0668 (0.3502) [0.191]  −0.0393 (0.110) [−0.356] 
Dum0810p  −0.1611 (0.02433) [−6.62]  −0.01164 (0.0363) [−0.320]  0.0174 (0.3682) [0.0473]  0.1631 (0.1159) [1.41] 
Dum0901p  −0.0058 (0.02565) [−0.227]  −0.2303 (0.0383) [−6.01]  −0.5219 (0.3881) [−1.34]  0.1623 (0.1222) [1.33] 
(e) Mexico
Variable equation  DLEmbi_mx  Diai  Dinf  DLDebt_X 
DLEmbi_mx_1  0.1148 (0.0752) [1.53]  0.9876 (11.12) [0.0888]  −3.0817 (1.039) [−2.97]  −0.5085 (0.3859) [−1.32] 
DLEmbi_mx_2  −0.4156 (0.0714) [−5.82]  10.1342 (10.56) [0.960]  0.8405 (0.9866) [0.852]  −0.4222 (0.3665) [−1.15] 
DLEmbi_mx_3  0.0448 (0.0774) [0.580]  29.4665 (11.45) [2.57]  −0.8210 (1.069) [−0.768]  −1.5534 (0.3973) [−3.91] 
DLiai_1  −0.0004 (0.0006) [−0.679]  −0.8000 (0.1026) [−7.80]  0.0213 (0.0095) [2.22]  0.0046 (0.0035) [1.30] 
DLiai_2  0.0004 (0.0008) [0.602]  −0.5716 (0.1198) [−4.77]  0.0207 (0.0111) [1.86]  0.0027 (0.0041) [0.663] 
DLiai_3  0.0001 (0.0006) [0.242]  −0.3033 (0.1031) [2.94]  0.0079 (0.0096) [0.82]  −0.0017 (0.0035) [−0.486] 
Dinf_1  −0.0070 (0.0098) [−0.716]  1.0485 (1.452) [0.722]  0.3456 (0.1356) [2.55] [1.34]  −0.1244 (0.0503) [−2.47] 
Dinf_2  0.0132 (0.0088) [1.49]  −0.9278 (1.315) [−0.706]  0.2636 (0.1228) [2.15]  −0.0649 (0.0456) [−1.42] 
Dinf_3  0.0017 (0.0070) [0.252]  0.4255 (1.045) [0.407]  0.2831 (0.0975) [2.90]  0.0252 (0.0362) [0.696] 
DLDebt_X_1  −0.0080 (0.0203) [−0.393]  −4.9697 (3.009) [−1.65]  0.2667 (0.2811) [0.949]  −0.2910 (0.1044) [−2.79] 
DLDebt_X_2  0.0114 (0.0214) [0.533]  −6.9052 (3.165) [−2.18]  1.3002 (0.2957) [4.40]  0.0324 (0.1098) [0.296] 
DLDebt_X_3  0.0293 (0.0214) [1.37]  −11.0014 (3.165) [−3.48]  0.0677 (0.2957) [0.229]  0.1342 (0.1099) [1.22] 
CI(1)_1*  0.0003 (0.0112) [0.0270]  1.4923 (1.661) [0.898]  −0.9421 (0.1552) [−6.07]  0.1206 (0.0576) [2.09] 
Dum0810p  −0.1394 (0.0161) [−8.66]  −0.5771 (2.379) [−0.243]  0.0734 (0.2223) [0.331]  −0.0255 (0.0825) [−0.309] 
Dum0405p  −0.0605 (0.0164) [−3.68]  −2.3491 (2.431) [−0.966]  −0.1993 (0.2271) [−0.878]  −0.0531 (0.0843) [−0.630] 
(f) Ecuador
Variable equation  DLEmbi_ec  DLeai  Dinf  DLDebt_X 
DLEmbi_ec_1  0.2528 (0.072) [3.50]  −0.086 (0.1061) [−0.819]  −0.0027 (0.0039) [−0.700]  −0.2698 (0.1149) [−2.35] 
DLeai_1  −0.031 (0.0604) [−0.527]  −0.6107 (0.088) [−6.88]  −0.0080 (0.0033) [−2.42]  0.0937 (0.096) [0.0976] 
Dinf_1  1.0619 (1.017) [1.04]  −0.1161 (1.493) [−0.077]  −0.1312 (0.055) [−2.35]  −1.504 (1.616) [−0.931] 
DLDebt_X_1  0.125 (0.0613) [2.04]  −0.0820 (0.089) [−0.911]  0.0009 (0.0033) [0.273]  −0.2481 (0.097) [−2.55] 
CI(1)_1*  −0.6925 (1.073) [−0.645]  0.0627 (1.575) [0.0399]  −0.4235 (0.059) [−7.17]  −0.7155 (1.705) [−0.42] 
Dum0109p  0.0125 (0.0569) [0.221]  0.0596 (0.083) [0.714]  0.013 (0.0031) [4.22]  −0.089 (0.09) [−0.987] 
Dum0301p  0.083 (0.056) [1.46]  0.0077 (0.083) [0.0931]  0.017 (0.0031) [5.43]  0.0109 (0.09) [0.121] 
Dum0810p  −0.4618 (0.058) [−7.93]  −0.1432 (0.0854) [−1.68]  −0.0047 (0.0032) [−1.49]  0.200 (0.092) [2.16] 
Dum0811p  −0.4984 (0.065) [−7.62]  −0.0083 (0.096) [−0.08]  −0.0071 (0.0035) [−1.97]  0.0721 (0.1039) [0.69] 
Dum0906p  0.1389 (0.056) [2.46]  −0.0377 (0.082) [−0.455]  −0.0007 (0.0031) [−0.257]  −0.410 (0.089) [−4.92] 
(g) Panama
Variable equation  DLEmbi_pa  DLrev_c  Dinf  DLDebt_X 
DLEmbi_pa_1  0.2995 (0.074) [4.00]  0.04671 (0.1630) [0.287]  3.8661 (1.595) [2.42]  −0.4881 (0.6171) [−0.791] 
DLrev_c_1  −0.0387 (0.0456) [−0.849]  −0.1722 (0.0992) [−1.74]  0.7122 (0.9714) [0.733]  0.1170 (0.3757) [0.311] 
Dinf_1  −0.0058 (0.0043) [−1.33]  −0.0228 (0.0095) [−2.40]  −0.2284 (0.093) [−2.45]  0.0769 (0.036) [2.14] 
DLDebt_X_1  −0.00147 (0.01302) [−0.113]  0.0337 (0.02832) [1.19]  0.6640 (0.2772) [2.40]  −0.0085 (0.1072) [−0.919] 
CI(1)_1*  −0.0988 (0.028) [−3.51]  0.1816 (0.0612) [2.97]  −0.0633 (0.5992) [−0.106]  −0.1927 (0.2318) [−0.832] 
CI(2)_1*  0.0067 (0.0092) [0.737]  0.00694 (0.0200) [0.346]  −0.9952 (0.1964) [−5.07]  −0.2118 (0.0759) [−2.79] 
Dum0401p  0.02503 (0.02011) [1.25]  −0.00535 (0.0437) [−0.122]  −1.9271 (0.4283) [−4.50]  0.3987 (0.1656) [2.41] 
Dum0810p  −0.1819 (0.0202) [−8.99]  0.0221 (0.044) [0.0502]  −0.4506 (0.4310) [−1.05]  0.1666 (0.1667) [1.00] 

Notes: Std-errors are in parenthesis and t-values in brackets. *Argentina: CI(1)=Inf.

Notes: Std-errors are in parenthesis and t-values in brackets.*Brazil: CI(1)=Lii - 0.18221*Inf+0.1918*LDebt_X.

Notes: Std-errors are in parentheses and t-values in brackets. *Colombia: CI(1)=LEMBI_co – 1.0232*LIMACO – 2.4449*Inf.

Notes: Std-errors are in parentheses and t-values in brackets. *Chile: C(1)=LEMBI_ch+0.07898*LDebt_X – 0.2549*Inf. **When non-significant dummies were excluded this coefficient becomes significant.

Notes: Std-errors are in parentheses and t-values in brackets. *Mexico: C(1)=Inf.

Notes: Std-errors are in parentheses and t-values in brackets. *Ecuador: CI(1)=Inf_1.

Notes: Std-errors are in parentheses and t-values in brackets. *Panama: CI(1)=-0.79176*Lrev_c+LEmbi_pana and CI(2)=0.61532*Inf+LDebt_X – 0.44483*LRev_c.

4.2Interpretation of the results

As mentioned, the results of the parameter estimations that describe the short run effects over variables are presented in Table 9a–g. Specifically, Table 9a–e correspond to non-dollarized countries and Table 9f and g to the dollarized ones (Ecuador and Panama). In these tables, the presence of t-values makes it easy to distinguish between significant and non-significant coefficients across the seven emerging countries in the sample.

Table 10 presents the comparative analysis of the seven emerging countries.

Table 10.

Comparative analysis taking only the significant coefficients into account.

Variable  Argentina  Brazil  Colombia  Chile  Mexico  Ecuador  Panama 
Dependent variable: DLEMBI_specific_country
DLEMBI   
DLEAI             
DINF               
DLDEBT_X             
DUM0810 
DUM0405         
DUM0211             
CI()            X(CI1) (CI(1)) 
Dependent variable: DLEAI*
DLEMBI  X(**)     
DLEAI     
DINF           
DDEBT_X           
DUM0810             
DUM0901           
CI()          X(CI1) 
Dependent variable: DINF
DLEMBI         
DLEAI       
DINF   
DLDEBT_X           
DUM0810             
CI()      X(CI2) (CI(2)) 
Dependent variable: DLDEBT_X
DLEMBI     
DLEAI             
DINF         
DLDEBT_X     
DUM0211             
DUM0810             
CI()          X(CI2) (CI(2)) 

Note: The results shown are the ones obtained when non-significant dummies were eliminated. CI(): Specifies only the variables included in each long run relationship, which are described in Table 8. *This variable changes depending on the country (see Table 4). **When non-significant dummies were excluded this coefficient becomes significant.

Looking across the columns in Table 9a–g, the following conclusions can be drawn: (1) The Emerging Bond Market Index (EMBI) is generally affected by global factors (proxied by dum0810p which captures the beginning of the financial crisis) and their own shocks, since all the countries in the sample, except Colombia, have a significant lagged DLEMBI coefficient in their EMBI equations. Debt_x does not seem to be relevant for explaining the EMBI behaviour, unless a country has defaulted on its debt obligations (as Ecuador did); (2) Economic activity is affected by the EMBI in all countries but dollarized ones; which represents the first important finding of this study, suggesting that in non-dollarized countries, debt-servicing costs may have an important impact on the evolution of the economy; (3) In most cases, inflation follows a long run relationship. In our opinion, this is the second important finding of this research, since it means that a country does not need to be dollarized to reach stable inflation levels. Inflation targeting might be behind the non-dollarized countries’ results19; (4) In general, investors look at the evolution of the EMBI to make their next decisions regarding sovereign bond debt investment. Colombia and Panama are the exceptions; (5) In general, the EMBI does not follow a long run relationship (with the exception of Mexico and Panama). (6) Finally, it seems that contagion effects are present in only three countries: Colombia, Chile, and Mexico. These inter-relationships are captured by dum0405p and dum0901p variables. The former affects the EMBI in the three countries, whilst the latter affects the economic activity in just the first two countries.

5Conclusions

The two main findings of this paper are: (i) economic activity is affected by the EMBI in all the countries except the dollarized ones; and (ii) inflation follows a long run relationship for most of the sample (the exceptions being Colombia and Chile), showing that a country does not need to be dollarized to achieve a stable inflation level. Our results suggest that in Latin America countries the pricing of risk (EMBI) depends mostly on global factors. Nevertheless, its evolution affects foreign lenders’ prospective debt investments, as well as domestic economic activity, except in dollarized countries.

These results may suggest the following conclusions. First, dollarization may ensure that currency mismatches will not occur during domestic economic crises; thus, the EMBI is more stable and these countries’ access to debt markets is easier due to their lower vulnerability to EMBI shocks. Second, dollarized countries are not as dependent on international reserves (they use the US dollar both to develop their economies and to pay their debts), as their non-dollarized counterparts which need international reserves to pay their debts but use national currencies to develop their economies. This comparative analysis between two dollarized and five non-dollarized countries suggests that dollarization may isolate the evolution of the broadest emerging market debt benchmark, the EMBI. These results are particularly interesting since there are some non-dollarized Latin American countries which are already doing (relatively) well on their own. We think that they should encourage fiscal discipline in order to avoid a debt crisis situation since, in a default context, due to the interrelationship between their economic activity and the EMBI evolution; they would face much more trouble than dollarized economies.

Besides, our results also suggest that in the long run, non-dollarized countries with inflation targeting policies achieve similar levels of inflation to those obtained by their dollarized counterparts. This result is consistent with those presented by other authors (Bernanke and Mishkin, 1997; Bernanke et al., 1999). The novelty is to reach this conclusion by means of the cointegrated VAR approach which identifies long-run relationships, including a stationary inflation variable in non-dollarized countries.

Acknowledgments

Financial support from Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness through grant ECO2016-76203 and through Plan Estatal de Investigación Científica y Técnica y de Innovación is gratefully acknowledged. The authors would like to thank Katarina Juselius for their useful and interesting comments and suggestions.

References
[Aizenman et al., 2013]
J. Aizenman, Y. Jinjarak, D. Park.
Fundamentals and sovereign risk of emerging markets.
(2013),
NBER Working Paper 18963
[Baldacci et al., 2008]
E. Baldacci, S. Gupta, A. Mati.
Is it (Still) mostly fiscal? Determinants of sovereign spreads in emerging markets.
(2008),
IMF Working Paper 1–23
[Bernanke and Mishkin, 1997]
B.S. Bernanke, F.S. Mishkin.
Inflation targeting: a new framework for monetary policy?.
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11 (1997), pp. 97-116
[Bernanke et al., 1999]
B.S. Bernanke, T. Laubach, F.S. Mishkin, A.S. Posen.
Inflation Targeting: Lessons from International Experience.
Princeton University Press, (1999),
[Caceres et al., 2010]
C. Caceres, G. Vicenzo, M. Segoviano Basurto.
Sovereign spreads: global risk aversion, contagion or fundamentals.
(2010),
IMF Working paper WP/10/120
[Corbo and Schmidt-Hebbel, 2001]
V. Corbo, K. Schmidt-Hebbel.
Inflation Targeting in Latino America.
Central Bank of Chile, (2001),
Working Papers, N° 105
[Délano and Selaive, 2005]
V. Délano, J. Selaive.
Spread soberanos, una aproximación factorial.
Central Bank of Chile Working Papers N° 309, (2005),
[Diaz Weigel and Gemmill, 2006]
D. Diaz Weigel, G. Gemmill.
What drives credit risk in emerging markets. The role of country fundamentals and market co-movements.
Journal of International Money and Finance, 25 (2006), pp. 476-502
[Domowitz et al., 1998]
I. Domowitz, J. Glen, A. Madhavan.
Country and currency risk premia in an emerging market.
The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 33 (1998), pp. 189-216
[Eaton and Gersowitz, 1981]
J. Eaton, M. Gersowitz.
Debt with potential repudiation: theoretical and empirical analysis.
Review of Economic Studies, XLVIII (1981), pp. 289-309
[ECLAC, 2002]
ECLAC.
Estudio Económico de América Latina y el Caribe: Argentina, 2001–2002.
(2002),
[ECLAC, 2004]
ECLAC.
Estudio Económico de América Latina y el Caribe: Panama, 2003–2004.
(2004),
[ECLAC, 2009]
ECLAC.
Estudio Económico de América Latina y el Caribe: Colombia, 2008–2009.
(2009),
[Edwards, 1986]
S. Edwards.
The pricing of Bonds and Bank loans in International markets. An empirical analysis of developing countries’ foreign borrowing.
European Economic Review, 30 (1986), pp. 565-589
[Eichengreen and Mody, 1998]
B. Eichengreen, A. Mody.
What explains changing spreads on emerging market debt: fundamentals or market sentiment?.
(1998),
NBER Working Paper 6408
[Feder and Just, 1977]
G. Feder, R. Just.
A study of debt servicing capacity applying logit-analysis.
Journal of Development Economics, 4 (1977), pp. 25-38
[Fracasso, 2007]
A. Fracasso.
The role of foreign and domestic factors in the evolution of the Brazilian EMBI spread and debt dynamics.
(2007),
HEI Working paper 22/2007
[Frank and Cline, 1971]
C. Frank, W. Cline.
Measurement of debt servicing capacity: an application of discriminant analysis.
Journal of International Economics, 1 (1971), pp. 327-344
[Giambiagi and Ronci, 2004]
F. Giambiagi, M. Ronci.
Fiscal policy and debt sustainability: Cardoso's Brazil, 1995–2002.
(2004),
IMF Working paper WP/04/156
[Gónzalez-Rozada and Levy Yeyati, 2008]
M. Gónzalez-Rozada, E. Levy Yeyati.
Global factors and emerging market spreads.
The Economic Journal, 118 (2008), pp. 1917-1936
[Hornbeck, 2013]
J.F. Hornbeck.
Argentina's Defaulted Sovereign Debt: Dealing with the Holdouts.
CRS Report for Congress, Congressional Research Service, (2013), pp. 7-5700
[Hoti and McAller, 2004]
S. Hoti, M. McAller.
An empirical assessment of country risk ratings and associated models.
Journal of Economic Surveys, 18 (2004), pp. 539-588
[IMF, 2010]
IMF.
Panama Selected Issues.
(2010),
IMF Country Report N° 10/315
[Johansen, 1996]
S. Johansen.
Likelihood-Based Inference in Cointegrated Vector Autoregressive Models. Advanced Texts in Econometrics.
2nd ed., Oxford University Press, (1996),
[Juselius, 2006]
K. Juselius.
The Cointegrated VAR Model: Methodology and Applications.
1st ed., Oxford University Press, (2006),
[Kamin and Von Kleist, 1999]
S. Kamin, K. Von Kleist.
The evolution and determinants of emerging markets credit spreads in the 1990s.
(1999),
BIS Working Paper 68
[Kaminsky and Schmukler, 2001]
G. Kaminsky, S. Schmukler.
Short and long run integration: do capital controls matter.
(2001),
Policy Research Working Paper N° 2660
[Kaminsky et al., 2009]
G. Kaminsky, A. Mati, N. Choueiri.
Thirty years of currency crisis in Argentina: external shocks or domestic fragility.
(2009),
NBER Working Paper Series N° 15478
[Krayenbuehl, 1985]
T.E. Krayenbuehl.
Country Risk: Assessment and Monitoring.
Lexington Books, (1985),
[Krugman, 2013]
P. Krugman.
Do currency regime matter?.
The New York Times, (2013),
Available at http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/10/19/do-currency-regimes-matter/?_r=1
[Lindao Jurado and Erazo Blum, 2009]
K.E. Lindao Jurado, J.C. Erazo Blum.
Riesgo país Ecuador: Principales determinantes y su incidencia.
(2009),
Available at: http://www.dspace.espol.edu.ec/bitstream/123456789/3886/1/6413.pdf
[López Herrera et al., 2013]
F. López Herrera, F. Venegas Martínez, C. Gurrola Ríos.
EMBI+Mexico y su relación dinámica con otros factores de riesgo sistemático: 1997–2011.
Estudios Económicos, 28 (2013), pp. 193-216
[Maltritz and Molchanov, 2013]
D. Maltritz, A. Molchanov.
Analyzing determinants of bonds yield with Bayesian Model Averaging.
Journal of Banking and Finance, 37 (2013), pp. 5275-5284
[Mathur et al., 2002]
I. Mathur, K.C. Gleason, S. Dibooglu, M. Singh.
Contagion effects from the 1994 Mexican Peso Crisis: evidence from Chilean stocks.
The Financial Review, 37 (2002), pp. 17-34
[McGuire and Schrijvers, 2003]
P. McGuire, M. Schrijvers.
Common factors in emerging market spreads.
BIS Quarterly Review, (2003),
[Morgan, 1999]
J.P. Morgan.
Introducing the JP Morgan Emerging Markets Bond Index Global (EMBI Global).
Methodology Brief, (1999),
[Mourelle, 2010]
J. Mourelle.
Financial Shocks and Macroeconomic Policies During the Argentine Crisis of 2001–2002.
Institut de Recherches Economiques et Sociales de l’Université Catholique de Louvain, (2010),
Discussion paper 2010–24
[Nogués and Grandes, 2001]
J. Nogués, M. Grandes.
Country risk: economic policy, contagions effect or political noise?.
Journal of Applied Economics, IV (2001), pp. 125-162
[OECD, 2012]
OECD.
Transition of the OECD CLI system to a GDP-based business cycle tarjet.
OECD Composite Leading Indicators, (2012),
[Rose, 2013]
A. Rose.
Surprising similarities: recent monetary regimes of small economies.
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper N° 19632, (2013),
[Rowland and Torres, 2004]
P. Rowland, J. Torres.
Determinants of spreads and Credit worthiness for emerging market debt: a panel data study.
Bank of the Republic of Colombia, Borradores de Economía N° 295, (2004),
[Rubinstein, 1999]
G. Rubinstein.
Dolarización. Argentina en la Aldea Global.
Grupo Editor Latinoamericano, (1999),
[Sandoval and Weisbrot, 2009]
L. Sandoval, M. Weisbrot.
Update on the Ecuadorian Economy.
Center for Economic and policy research, (2009),
[Schmukler, 2002]
S.L. Schmukler.
Pricing currency risk under currency boards.
Journal of Development Economics, 69 (2002), pp. 367-391
[Schuknecht et al., 2009]
L. Schuknecht, J. Von Hagen, G. Wolswijk.
Government risk premium in the bond market: EMU and Canada.
European Journal of Political Economy, 25 (2009), pp. 371-384
[Schuknecht et al., 2010]
L. Schuknecht, J. Von Hagen, G. Wolswijk.
Government risk premium in the EU revisited – the impact of the financial crisis.
(2010),
ECB Working Paper Series N° 1152
[Vargas et al., 2012]
H. Vargas, A. González, I. Lozano.
Macroeconomic effects of structural fiscal policy changes in Colombia.
(2012),
BIS Paper N° 67

Financial support from Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness through grant ECO2016-76203 and through Plan Estatal de Investigación Científica y Técnica y de Innovación is gratefully acknowledged. The authors would like to thank Katarina Juselius for their useful and interesting comments and suggestions.

The results are not conclusive, though. Whilst Krugman (2013) shows how Eurozone members have had more trouble managing their debts than countries outside it, Rose (2013) suggests that the exchange rate regime does not matter.

The JP Morgan Emerging Markets Bonds Index Global tracks total returns for traded external debt instruments in emerging markets. The EMBI Global includes US dollar-denominated Brady bonds, loans, and Eurobonds with an outstanding face value of at least $500 million. Daily historical index levels have been reported since December 31, 1993. See Morgan (1999) for more details.

Country risk refers to the likelihood that a sovereign state (borrower) may be unable and/or unwilling to meet its obligations towards foreign lenders and/or investors (Krayenbuehl, 1985).

The literature on country risk is essentially four decades old. The two pioneering articles were published by Frank and Cline (1971) and Feder and Just (1977). Since then, authors have attempted to establish the determinants and the econometric criteria to estimate, evaluate, and forecast country risk in different economies.

In financial jargon, the investors’ degree of risk aversion is usually called “investor appetite for risk”.

See Hoti and McAller (2004) and Maltritz and Molchanov (2013), which present a summary of the explanatory variables and econometric models used in previously published empirical articles.

The Economic Activity Index for Argentina, Ecuador and Colombia is presented as the monthly proxy of GDP by their respective National Statistic Institutes. In the case of Mexico we use the Industrial Activity Index instead of the Global Economic Activity Index because the latter, not only does not include all the sectors of the economy, but also is still a preliminary variable that is being adjusted by private and public enterprises over time. Indeed, in Mexico, the Industrial Index has historically been used as a proxy of GDP because their strong co-movements (OECD, 2012). Brazil and Chile models include the Industrial Index as well, but this time the reason is data availability constraint.

This section relies heavily on Juselius (2006).

In April 1991 the Convertibility Plan was launched, which pegged the peso 1-to-1 to the US dollar. This plan was replaced with a dual exchange rate regime based on an official exchange rate of 1.4 pesos per dollar for public sector and tradable transactions, while other transactions were conducted at market rates. By June 2002 the exchange rate reached 4 pesos per dollar (Kaminsky et al., 2009; Mourelle, 2010).

In June 2009 the Correa government defaulted on $3.2 billion of foreign public debt, and then completed a buyback of 91 per cent of the defaulted bonds (Sandoval and Weisbrot, 2009).

Inflation only achieved a stable level in Ecuador after the first quarter of 2003.

Several articles have presented empirical evidence of contagion effects within these countries. For instance, based on the estimation of a multivariate regression model, Mathur et al. (2002) conclude that there were spillover contagion effects from the Mexican market to the Chilean market during the 1994 peso crisis. Moreover, Kaminsky and Schmukler (2001) study whether capital controls affect the link between domestic and foreign stock market prices and interest rates, and find that equity prices are more internationally linked than interest rates.

McGuire and Schrijvers (2003) find high correlations of common factors with S&P500, US Treasury yield curve and oil prices.

On the supply side, when Treasury bond rates go up, the increased debt servicing cost decreases the supply of US external debt. This in turn increases the price of emerging bonds averaged by the EMBI.

The first four steps were performed using the software CATS. Recursive estimation to check parameters stability is available under request.

This econometric work was carried out with the software Ox Metrics.

Corbo and Schmidt-Hebbel (2001) analyze the experience of Latin America countries with inflation targeting regimes and classify Brazil and Chile as full-fledged inflation targeting, whilst Colombia and Mexico are classified as partial inflation targeting regimes. These authors emphasize the substantial progress of these countries to achieve low one digit inflation levels without output sacrifices.

Copyright © 2016. Asociación Cuadernos de Economía
Article options
Tools